Benefits of Initiatives

Better Policy

Ballot initiatives allow citizens to enact meaningful policy changes that otherwise have little chance of being passed by politicians.

Legislator Competition

The initiative process helps hold government accountable to the people.

Higher Voter Turnout

Ballot initiatives and referendums creates more interest, therefore higher voter turnout, in elections.

Beating Big Money

Ballot initiatives and referendums help citizens overcome well-funded special interests.

Better Policy

Ballot initiatives allow citizens to enact meaningful policy changes that otherwise have little chance of being passed by politicians.Just like legislators, voters can pass bad laws or fail to pass good ones. But historically, voters have a far better record.

Large, diverse groups of independent people make better decisions. James Surowiecki’s award-winning book, The Wisdom of Crowds has shown how large groups of decision-makers more often yield better policy outcomes than unaccountable politicians.

Better Tax Policy

States where citizens enjoy initiative and referendum rights not only have lower taxes, they also have more tax and spending decisions made at the local level, rather than statewide. Furthermore, a recent study by scholars at Wellesley College says I&R states have significantly less government waste and better economic performance than do states without I&R.

Resources

Fiscal Implications of the Initiative Process
Initiatives led to significantly lower spending and taxes. Per capita spending, for example, was about $83 per capita lower in a typical initiative state than a typical non-initiative state, which translates into $332 less expenditure (and hence taxes and fees) for a family of four. Compared to the average level of state and local spending, $2,300 per capita, initiatives caused a reduction of 4 percent.

Have Voter Initiatives Paralyzed the California Budget? by John G. Matsusaka of the University of Southern California and the Initiative & Referendum Institute.
Professor Matsusaka concludes that, “the initiative process is a scapegoat for the inability of elected officials to manage the competing demands for public funds in a period of declining revenue.”

Limiting Government: Through Direct Democracy by Michael New.
“State legislatures have occasionally imposed tax and expenditure limitations (TELs) on themselves. TELs passed by initiative are more restrictive and contain fewer loopholes than those enacted by state legislatures. Regression analysis of a comprehensive data set of state government spending shows that TELs enacted by citizen initiatives cause per capita public spending to decrease; TELs enacted by state legsialtures are associated with an increase in government expenditures,” writes Michael New.

By Popular Demand by Pete Sepp of the National Taxpayers Union.
“Arguably the Initiative and Referendum has contributed more to fiscal restraint than any other procedural device or substantive action?.This process has given at least some Americans a choice between meaningless elections and outright revolution, ironically providing the very kind of political stability that critics say I&R seeks to upset,” writes Pete Sepp.

The Impact of Voter Initiatives on Economic Activity: a Wellesley College Working Paper by S. Brock Blomberg, Gregory D. Hess, and Akila Weerapana.
“Our findings suggest that states with initiative systems waste between 20 to 30 percent fewer resources than do non-initiative states resulting in better economic performance?”

Fiscal Effects of the Voter Initiative: Evidence from the Last 30 Years by John G. Matsusaka of the University of Southern California.

Beating Big Money

People are far less swayed by money than politicians are. Multiple studies reveal that citizens tend to favor “grassroots” initiatives over “big money” initiatives, whereas legislatures usually vote on the side of big money. Special interests may be able to pay to play with elected officials, but it’s far more difficult to bribe a majority of the voters of a state. As just one example, that citizens of California enacted term limits despite being outspent by more than a 6 to 1 margin.

Initiative and referendum helps citizens overcome the big-money advantage many special interests currently enjoy. No wonder well-funded special interests oppose initiative and referendum, because they so often dominate the current political process in state legislatures, while having had little success with I&R.

More money is always an advantage over less money, but studies dramatically show that money plays a much smaller role in I&R than in candidate races. Wealthy interests are simply not able to pass initiatives by outspending opponents, nor to block citizen-led measures.

Professor Liz Gerber of the University of Michigan has studied the role of money in the initiative process. In her book, The Populist Paradox (Princeton University Press, 1999), she analyzed surveys of interest group activities and motivations, as well as campaign finance records from 168 different direct legislation campaigns in eight states. Her research concluded economic interest groups are severely limited in their ability to pass new laws by initiative. Simply put, money is necessary but not sufficient for success at the ballot box. By contrast, research found that citizen groups with broad-based support can much more effectively use direct legislation to pass new laws. When they are able to mobilize sufficient financial resources to get out their message, citizen groups are much more successful at the ballot box, even when economic interest groups greatly outspend them.

Voters become skeptical when a large amount of money is spent trying to pass an initiative. Real world results show that the more money spent on passing an initiative, the less likely the initiative is to win. The initiative and referendum process is a place where the side with the most money doesn’t necessarily win. I&R is critical in allowing citizens with a needed reform or a better idea to overcome big money opposition.

Resources

I&R Institute: “What Impact Does Money Have In The Initiative Process?”

The initiative process presents an environment that consistently allows financial advantages to be offset by other political assets. Separate studies by Daniel Lowenstein and David Magleby show that even when proponents of initiatives outspend opponents by a two-to-one margin or more, most of these “big spending” measures lose at the ballot box.

—“The Initiative Process: Where People Count” by Paul Jacob from the book Taking the Initiative, edited by Larry Sabato

Important Court Decisions on Money in Initiative Campaigns

U.S. Supreme Court

Buckley v. Valeo, 424 U.S. 1 (1976)
Landmark First Amendment protection case pertaining to campaign spending. The ruling helped establish the fact that spending on ballot measure campaigns cannot be limited.

Citizens Against Rent Control v. Berkeley, 454 U.S. 290 (1981) Appeal from the Supreme Court of California, No. 80-737. Argued October 14, 1981, decided December 14, 1981
The U.S. Supreme Court held that a California city’s ordinance to impose a limit on contributions to committees formed to support or oppose ballot measures violated the First Amendment. The Court based its decision on the right of individuals to bear and obtain information. In doing so, it equated free political spending with free speech.

First National Bank of Boston v. Bellotti, 435 U.S. 765 (1978) APPEAL FROM THE SUPREME JUDICIAL COURT OF MASSACHUSETTS, No. 76-1172. Argued November 9, 1977, decided April 26, 1978
The Supreme Court has supported the notion that one-sided spending is not a crucial factor in ballot issue elections. In this case, the U.S. Supreme Court invalidated a Massachusetts statute prohibiting business corporations from making contributions or expenditures “… for the purpose of … influencing or affecting the vote on any question submitted to the voters, other than one materially affecting any of the property, business or assets of the corporation.”

State Courts

Citizens for Jobs and Energy v. Fair Political Practices Commission, 16 Cal.3d 671 (1976) [S.F. No. 23391. Supreme Court of California. April 7, 1976.]
The California Supreme Court declared that the Political Reform Act couldn’t limit expenditures by ballot measure committees.

Hardie v. Eu, 18 Cal.3d 371 (1976) S.F. No. 23450. Supreme Court of California. November 29, 1976.
The California Supreme Court found unconstitutional the Political Reform Act’s cap on expenditures for qualifying ballot measures since it violated First Amendment rights.

Michigan Chamber of Commerce v. Austin, 832 F. 2d 947 (1987)
The federal appellate court ruled that Michigan’s provisions limiting corporate contributions to ballot measure campaigns violated the right of association and free speech guarantees of the First Amendment. Another portion of the Michigan statute, prohibiting corporations from making independent expenditures on behalf of political candidates from general treasury funds, was upheld by the U.S. Supreme Court in Austin v. Michigan State Chamber of Commerce, U.S., ll0 S. Ct. 1391 (1990)

Montana Chamber of Commerce v. Argenbright, U.S. 9th 98-36256 (2000) U.S. 9th Circuit of Appeals 98-36256, Opinion issued September 26, 2000
The court of appeals affirmed judgments of the district court. The court held that the First Amendment does not permit restricting corporate expenditures as a means of expression on public issues presented through a state’s ballot initiative process.

Higher Voter Turnout

Studies have consistently shown that entrusting citizens with the ballot initiative process results in more people voting.

In their study, The Effects of Ballot Initiatives on Voter Turnout in the American States, Caroline Tolbert and John Grummel of Kent State University and Daniel Smith of the University of Denver found that states with the initiative process experienced higher voter turnout.

During the 1990s, voter turnout was 7% to 9% greater in midterm elections and 3% to 4.5% higher in presidential elections in states that have the initiative process over those that do not.

Legislator Competition

Initiatives foster competition for legislators. Allowing citizens to challenge bad laws or introduce new laws puts a much-needed check on the monopoly power of state legislatures. In this way, the initiative helps hold government accountable to the people.

Perhaps more importantly, instead of covering up their mistakes, citizens have the incentive to fix them. Whereas legislators often try to hide their personal mistakes to protect their political careers, citizens just want to see the enactment of the best policies. Citizens actually feel the pain when policies don’t work.